1
To be cited as: New York: The Phelps-Stokes Fund, 1997
AFRICAN DEBT AND SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT:
Policies for Partnership with Africa
February 1997
Revised, March 1997
Haider A Khan
Graduate School of International Studies
University of Denver, Denver , CO 80208
e- mail: hkhan@du.edu
I would like to thank Lori Hartman and Go Ito for valuable research assistance.
I would also like to thank the participants of the seminar at the Phelps
- Stokes
Fund in
New York
City and
those who
sent their comments by e
- mail for their valuable
suggestions. All remaining errors are my own.
pg_0002
2
I
“The Washington Consensus” Travels to Africa
The Washington Consensus 5
The Washington Consensus and the Structural Adjustment
Policies in Africa 7
II
African Debt and Bleak Prospects for Sustainable Development
The Marginalization of Africa 7
Economic Conditions in Africa 8
Human Conditions in Africa and Sustainability 14
III
The Way Forward: Sustainable Development with Equity in Africa
African Capabilities 20
Assessment of SAPs from a Capability Perspective 21
An Alternative Structural Adjustment Program (ASAP)
for Capability-enhancement in Africa 25
Social Expenditure Conditionality for Africa
30
IV
Rethinking U.S. Economic Policy Toward Africa
A New Vision. 32
Need for Specificity 34
Some Specific Recommendations: A New
Economic Partnership with Africa 35
Appendix.
IMF and World Bank Adjustment Approaches:
Stylized Descriptions
39
pg_0003
3
Introduction
Economic Justice and Africa
The continent of Africa, especially Sub-Saharan Africa, faces a dire economic struggle.
1
Over the last decade in particular the living conditions for the great majority of the people there
have deteriorated. Economic growth is stagnant or even negative in many cases. The environment
has also deteriorated. Inequality and poverty among the population have increased. All these are
well-known facts -- acknowledged by both bilateral and multilateral donors of aid to Africa. Yet
there seems to be a lack of vision from which arises a lack of determination in helping the poor,
indebted African nations in their struggle against underdevelopment. What has brought about this
paralysis of policy.
In the following section I discuss the so-called “Washington Consensus” which seems to
be dictating much of the current policy gestures towards Africa and other poor indebted countries
in the third world. The indebted African countries are forced to swallow the bitter medicine of
structural adjustment regardless of their economic and human conditions.
2
The direct and indirect
costs of these policies on the vulnerable groups are already evident. We must ask if there is an
alternative to the current combination of structural adjustment prescribed by the multilateral
organizations on the one hand and the neo-isolationist retreat on the economic front by the U.S. on
the other.
According to the recent advances in the theory of human development the goal of
development is to enhance the scope of real freedom of individuals. Economists and philosophers
such as Amartya Sen and Martha Nussbaum have proposed that the enhancement of the
capabilities of the people -- their freedom to be and to do, to live their lives fully -- must be the
pg_0004
4
ultimate goal of development.
3
UNDP has published several volumes of Human Development
Reports to alert the international community about the achievements and shortfalls in all the
countries in this regard. Once again, measured by these indicators, the plight of African countries
would appear to call for urgent international action.
It can not be overemphasized that this is fundamentally an issue of global justice. Ignoring
the serious conditions of economic deprivation in Africa and elsewhere in the world only declares
our own complicity in an international regime of injustice. The call for an economic partnership
with Africa, therefore, is at the bottom a call for economic justice.
But even if we all can agree about the ethics of the situation, what kind of alternative
economic policies towards Africa are necessary. And, the skeptics might say, is it realistic to
advocate an alternative set of policies.
The burden of this monograph is to show clearly that what is morally and economically
necessary to do in this case can also be defended for its realism. To allow African economies to
sink into a morass of dependent stagnation is not ultimately good for the World Economy. It is also
not in the best interests of the U.S. to allow this to happen.
The argument is carried on in several stages. In the first section the received view
(called ’the Washington Consensus’) regarding the African adjustment (as well as elsewhere) is
critically reviewed. Next, the debt and human condition in sub-Saharan Africa are reviewed. Not
surprisingly, this reveals the glaring inconsistencies between present domestic and international
policy regimes and the real needs of the African people. In light of these discrepancies an
alternative structural adjustment program more in keeping with the human development goals of
Africa is outlined. The alternative program has deep economic and moral basis in enhancing the
pg_0005
5
capabilities and real freedom of the African citizens.
4
The final part of this monograph explores policy options for the U.S. with respect to Africa
in the sphere of international economic relations. It turns out that ignoring Africa or following a
policy of ’selective isolationism’ is not a viable option for the U.S. in the next century.
Realistically, the U.S. must forge a new partnership with Africa based on trust, mutual respect and
responsible economic behavior. A set of specific recommendations consistent with the principle
of enhancing the economic freedom and social capabilities of the African people concludes the
monograph with a note of cautious optimism for the future.
I
The “Washington Consensus” Travels to Africa
The “Washington Consensus”
“Washington Consensus” is the name given to the complex array of policy reforms
underway in the developing countries. John Williamson
5
can be credited with coining this aptly descriptive
term. Although, as Williamson
6
tells us he "...should have christened this list the 'universal convergence' rather
than the 'Washington consensus,' on the grounds that there is no complete consensus, while the very real
convergence extends far beyond Washington...." The impact of this so-called "Washington consensus" on the
world economy is already considerable. But what is this consensus about which not everyone agrees. In the
appendix to his excellent 1994 paper Williamson provides us with a list that without being exhaustive covers a
great deal of the policy terrain. In my view, this list is as good a place to begin the discussion on structural
adjustment as any other. I have reorganized the list to reflect (roughly) the priorities that African economies have
pg_0006
6
been asked to accord to the various components of the consensus. However, the ordering is definitely not
lexicographical and does not apply completely to any particular country.
(1) Privatization: Ways and means must be found for state enterprises to be privatized. A soft version
advocates caution and gradual privatization. A hard core neoliberal version advocates "shock treatment"
in the form of rapid and wholesale privatization.
(2) Deregulation: In keeping with the tenets of (an almost) perfectly competitive market structure,
governments should abolish regulations that get in the way of new firms entering the market. All
regulations that restrict competition in any way should be abolished.
(3) Property rights: Through a set of legal and institutional reforms private property rights must be secured by
law.
(4) Financial liberalization: The ultimate goal of deregulation and privatization of the financial sector is to
achieve free market interest rates. Williamson adds judiciously, "...experience has shown that, under
conditions of a chronic lack of confidence, market-determined rates can be so high as to threaten the
financial solvency of productive enterprises and government. Under that circumstance a sensible interim
objective is the abolition of preferential interest rates for privileged borrowers and achievement of a
moderately positive real interest rate."
7
(5) Trade liberalization: Here the GATT philosophy and procedures are advocated. As Williamson puts it,
"Quantitative trade restrictions should be rapidly replaced by tariffs, and these should be progressively
reduced until a uniform low tariff in the range of 10 per cent (or at most 20 per cent) is achieved. There is,
however, some disagreement about the speed with which tariffs should be reduced (with
recommendations falling in a band between 3 and 10 years), and about whether it is advisable to slow
down the process of liberalization when macroeconomic conditions are adverse (recession and payments
deficit).
8
(6) Foreign direct investment: Barriers to entry by the foreign firms should be removed. This is intended to
increase the capital in-flow to the African economies.
(7) Fiscal discipline: This is often seen as the heart of reforming the government sector.
9
According to
Williamson, "Budget deficits, properly measured to include those of provincial governments, state
enterprises, and the central bank, should be small enough to be financed without recourse to the inflation
tax. This typically implies a primary surplus (i.e., before adding debt service to expenditure) of several per
cent of GDP, and an operational deficit (i.e., disregarding that part of the interest bill that simply
compensates for inflation) of no more than about 2 per cent of GDP."
10
(8) Public expenditure priorities: Hand in hand with the fiscal discipline of the governments goes the task of
setting priorities in expenditure. The guideline is to use economic rather than political criteria for
allocating expenditures.
pg_0007
7
The Washington Consensus and the Structural Adjustment Policies in Africa
Many of these prescriptions also form the core of the structural adjustment policies (SAPs) recommended
by the IMF. The reader is referred to Appendix 1 for a description of SAPs and a mathematical formalization of
the IMF financial programming model.
Although neither the Washington consensus nor the IMF model is used as a complete blueprint for actual
policy formulation, more often than not they represent the philosophical and theoretical foundations of the analysis
underlying most policies for African economies. Given the complexities of the actual African economies and the
often confusing nature of the policy statements by the government officials in these countries the
Washington-consensus and the IMF approach both have at least the virtues of clarity and consistency. However,
the most significant question to ask is how appropriate are these policy approaches to the real problems of
stagnation, poverty and environmental decay in Africa. In order to answer this question fully we need to know
something about the problems faced by the African economies. In particular, in this monograph I wish to focus on
the problems of low-income African economies where the problems of indebtedness and sustainable development
are the most acute. I now turn to a critical discussion of the trends and conditions in Africa.
II
African Debt and Bleak Prospects for Sustainable Development
The Marginalization of Africa
pg_0008
8
Recently (5-8 August, 1996) twenty five African NGO networks met in Harare to discuss
the African development situation. These groups represent a wide-ranging spectrum of
development philosophies. Most of them also have grass-roots connections. Their conclusions
regarding the prospects for African development under the currently prevailing conditions, if
accurate, are truly alarming. According to the NGO groups:
The African continent continues to be marginalized in the new world order. It remains
characterized on the international scene as a basket case stricken with unresolvable poverty,
conflict and debt. At the same time, the shaping of development policy, practice and pace
is driven by the interests of Trans-National Corporations and dominated by new
instruments of global governance such as the World Trade Organization and International
Financial Institutions. These are dominated by the North at the expense of Africa’s voice.
The international community lacks the moral and political will to constructively assist
Africa with its dilemmas. It is therefore a matter of grave concern that, in spite of their best
efforts, African institutions have not adequately played their role in defining an agenda for
African development, in articulating African interests and in harnessing resources and
capacities for action.
At the national level, African governments have excluded people in the policy and
decision making processes. In particular, women, who are the socio-economic mainstay of
the continent, have been totally marginalized. The exclusion of the population has blocked
the emergence of endogenous initiatives. This is aggravated by the failure of education and
information systems to nurture positive and creative thought to address African problems
and mobilize local initiative.
11
The charges above are serious enough to merit a thorough investigation in the African
context. It is also necessary to understand the deeper reasons for the African decline and the
consequent “Afro-pessimism” that is in vogue nowadays.
12
Economic Conditions in Africa
Table 1 presents the growth record of the African countries during the decade of the 80's.
It is clear that the growth performance of all the countries has been quite weak. What is indeed
pg_0009
9
alarming is that the weakest economies that were called upon to adjust most strongly by the IMF
and the World Bank are precisely the ones registering a negative growth rate during the decade.
Table 1
Growth of GDP in Africa, 198O-1987 (constant 198O U.S. dollars, market prices, in percent)
Period
Country
1980- 1981- 1982- 1983- 1984- 1985- 1986- 1980
Groups
81 82 83 84 85 86 87 1987
Aver.
Strong
adjusting - 3.01 0.33 - 3.85 - 4.31 6.33 2.82 - 1.97 - 0.53
Weak
adjusting 5.44 3.46 0.66 - 1.29 0.13 4.01 1.88 2.00
Non- .
adjusting 3.92 3.35 3.53 3.68 6.40 3.62 - 2.51 3.50
Sub-Saharan
Africa - 1.05 1.01 - 2.37 - 2.94 5.44 3.09 - 1.48 0.24
North
I Africa - 2.27 3.12 3.63 2.78 1.90 0.19 1.29 1.50
Africa
Total - 1.52 1.81 - 0.06 - 0.66 3.98 1.92 - 0.38 0.73
Source: World Bank data files; country coverage and classification of strong adjusting, weak
adjusting and non
-adjusting countries according to World Bank; Average annual growth rates were
calculated as arith metic averages.
Table 2 shows other summary performance indicators over the same decade. Again, the
growth in export performance has been negative as has been the growth in real domestic
pg_0010
10
investment. The saving rate, by world standards, is quite low. At the same time the growth in
personal consumption has been negative. Therefore, it is not the profligacy of the ordinary people
in Africa that can account for the low saving rate (although the affluent minority certainly has
more than a few profligate members). The more likely explanation is the constraint of falling
income and the burden of indebtedness.
Table 2
Summary of Economic Performance Indicators (average annual percentage change unless
indicated otherwise)
Countries not
All Countries affected by strong
shocks
Period With strong With weak With strong
With weak
reform or no reform reform
or no reform
programs programs programs
prog rams
Growth of GDP
1980-84 1.4 1.5 1.2 0.7
(constant 1980 1985-37 2.8 2.7 3.8 1.5
prices)
Agricultural
1980-84 1.1 1.3 1.4 1.8
production 1985-87 2.6 1.5 3.4 2.6
Growth of
1980-84 - 1.3(-11.0) - 3.1(-0.9) - 0.7(-4.7) - 5.7(-2.1)
export volume
1985-87 4.2 ( -2.0) 0 2( -2.5) 4.9( 3.5)
- 3.3(-6.0)
Growth of imp.
1985-87 1.7 ( -7.7) - 2.7(-3.0) 6.1(7.4) - 4.o(-2· 2)
volume excluding oil
4.8 (6.8)
exporters
Growth of real
1980-84 - 8.1 - 3 7 - 3.5 - 7.0
domestic 1985-87 - 0.9 - 7 0 1.9 - 4.8
investment
pg_0011
11
Turning now to African indebtedness the situation in Sub-Saharan Africa in particular
appears to be grave. Table 3 shows the debt records of this region. Over the last decade the
absolute amount of debt service has shown mainly an upward trend. After 1986 there was some
decline, but recent tendency is for the debt service burden to grow once again. The debt service
ratio (ratio of debts to exports) stood at 278.4 for these very poor countries in 1990. Debt to GDP
ratio for the same year was 107.7. It is impossible to envisage sustainable development with equity
under such intolerable debt burden.
Table 3 Sub - Saharan African Debt
Debt Service (DS) DS to Debt To Debt
Years (USS Billions) Exports Exports to GDP
1978
3.5 10.0 102.3 24.3
1979
4.4 10.2 96.1 24.5
1980
6.2 10.8 85.0 23.5
1981
6.6 14.2 123.0 29.2
1982
6.8 17.8 177.2 34.4
1983
8.1 22.9 214.5 40.4
1984
10.2 26.9 207.7 41.9
1985
13.0 34.7 217.6 43.4
pg_0012
12
To make an already bad situation even worse the terms of trade have also declined for the
African countries in the last decade. Table 4 displays the statistics for a number of African
economies. If we assume a value of 100 for terms of trade in 1980 by 1988 all countries in the table
show a decline to various degrees. Terms of trade is defined by the international economists as the
ratio of export prices to prices of importables. Accordingly by the late 1980s some of the African
countries on the table had to increase exports by more than 25% to import the same amount as in
1980. If we add to this the debt service burden discussed above it is not surprising that investment
and growth have declined for most of these countries steadily.
Table 4 Terms of Trade Estimates for Selected African Countries
(1980 = 100)
Country 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988
Ghana
73 64 63 71 59 66 64 65
Kenya
93 92 88 92 91 91 73 72
Madagascar
84 82 88 102 103 110 83 81
Mozambique
103 89 85 101 94 90 83 87
Rwanda
68 67 63 68 71 70 52 53
SierraLeonc 90 90 93 98 97 99 89 90
Sudan 102 86 84 92 93 81 76 94
Cote d'Ivoire 90 71 83 80 78 73 74 82
pg_0013
13
Table 5 shows the human development indexes (HDI) for selected African countries. This
is intended to be a summary indicator of overall development performance. It takes into account
not just growth (increased income) but also the effects of growth on the other human development
aspects such as health and education. By this widely accepted measure most African countries are
behind even poor developing economies such as Ecuador or Philippines. According to the 1996
Human Development Report Ghana (rated by the World Bank as a recent
Table 5: Human Development in Africa
Real
Real GDP
GDP
per
per capita
HDI HDI
capita minus
value rank rank HDI
rank
Zimbabwe
0.534 124 120 -3
Congo
0.517 125 101 -23
Kenya
0.473 128 136 9
Ghana
0.467 129 124 -4
Lesotho 0.464 130 150 21
Equatorial Guinea
0.461 131 126 -4
Zambia
0.411 136 144 9
Nigeria 0.401 137 134 -2
Zaire 0.371 141 174 33
Tanzania,
0.364 144 170 26
Sudan
0.359 146 138 -7
Cote d'lvoire 0.357 147 131 -15
pg_0014
14
success in Africa) scored 0.467 with an overall rank of 129 among 174 countries. The country to
occupy the last rank was also an African country -- Niger with a value of 0.204 for its HDI index.
The silver lining in this otherwise completely dark cloud is that over the last three decades
Sub-Saharan African countries have slowly improved their human development record. However,
this improvement while worthy of acknowledgment especially in the light of disastrous growth in
the 80's has been at a snail’s pace. From 1980 to 1993 in particular the index increased from 0.312
to 0.379 -- not a record of phenomenal upward trend. It should also be noted that countries, with
only medium human development according to the UNDP had an average HDI of 0.647 for 1993
-- more than twice that recorded for Sub-Saharan Africa.
The decade of 1980's seems to have been really a lost decade for Sub-Saharan Africa in so
pg_0015
15
far as economic development is concerned. Over the entire decade GNP per capita fell by nearly
10 percent. World prices for major exports -- tea, cocoa, coffee and cotton fell by an enormous 50
percent. Real investment dropped by more than 50% in per capita terms. About 170 million people
-- nearly a third of the region’s population -- do not receive an adequate amount of food. About 23
million children are malnourished and 16% of the babies are underweight. The region also records
the world’s highest maternal mortality rate -- 929 per 100,000 live births (compared with 33 for the
OECD countries).
Human Conditions in Africa and Sustainability
Table 6 shows the bleak trends in health and nutrition indicators in Africa. Under these
circumstances the rhetoric of sustainable development may seem like a cruel joke and indeed
under the current circumstances this assessment is not far from the truth. However, as Khan and
Sonko
13
have shown improvement of the environment can under some circumstances go hand in
hand with an increase in equality and improvement of the standard of living of the poor people.
Table 6: Trends in Some Health and Nutrition Indicators
Infant mortality rate Daily calorie supply
(per thousand live births) (per capita)
Country
.
!965 1989 Annual
1965 1986 Annual
change (%)
change (%)
1. Burundi
142 70 -2.9 2 311 2 253 -0.2
2. CH 157 100 -1.9 2 016 1 980 -0.1
3. Cote d'lvoire 119 92 -2.0 2 334 2 365 0.1
4. Ghana
120 86 -1 1 1 912 2 209 0.6
5. Kenya 112 68 -2.1 2 169 1 973 0.4
6. Madagascar
201 117 -2.2 2 375 2 101 -0.5
7. Malawi
200 It7 -1.3 2 196 2 009 -0.4
8. Mali 207 167 -0.9 1 113 2 111 0.7
9. Mauritania 171 123 1.5 1 796 2 528 1.5
pg_0016
16
Currently, Africa faces multiple ecological challenges. The most significant and
threatening ones are: drought, deforestation, desertification and pollution. To this list one could
add hazardous waste dumping and possibly global warming.
Drought is a typical feature of the Sahelian countries. In the late sixties the Sahel suffered
one of the worst droughts in recorded history. Most affected were Ethiopia, Somalia, Mozambique
and the Sudan. The more recent droughts have forced mass starvation. In 1985 it was estimated
pg_0017
17
that more than 30 million people were in danger of starvation. More than 10 million people were
forced to abandon their homes and lands because of the adverse conditions caused by the drought.
Deforestation is also an imminent threat to the economic security in Africa. In 1991 the
U.N. report on Africa’s environment warned that deforestation was proceeding at the rate of 3.8
million hectares per year. In Sub-Saharan Africa, more than 30% of the original rainforest has been
degraded. In Nigeria, it is reported that more than 90% of its moist forests are already gone. Cote
d’Ivoire has already destroyed two thirds of its forest even as it continues logging for exporting
timber.
Poverty and deforestation are also linked by a vicious circle in Africa. The poor are forced
to degrade the environment by cutting down trees for agriculture, livestock raising and in many
cases for fire to cook their daily food. However, this in turn leads to lower opportunities for the
poor and a long-term decline of their income earning potential.
14
Closely related to deforestation is the threat of desertification. Aforementioned practices
such as logging, overgrazing and the destruction of trees for firewood contribute to desertification.
In the long run, this will make agriculture totally unsustainable.
The primary cause of desertification, however, is the overcultivation of cash crops such as
cotton, groundnuts and tobacco. Burkina Faso, for example, loses an area of 85,000 hectares each
year due to its cultivation of groundnuts and other cash crops. Senegal loses about 50,000 hectares
in the same way and Guinea Bissau degrades 20,000-35,000 hectares per year. A recent United
Nations Environment Program and FAO study on soil erosion points out that about 23% of African
land has been degraded. With the continuation of current trends in soil erosion African agricultural
output could decline by 25% by the year of 2000. This is sobering news for a continent faced with
pg_0018
18
many other human catastrophes already.
15
To these severe ecological challenges one can add the threat to the health and well-being
of people from the worsening of air and water quality and the increase in the dumping of hazardous
wastes by some non-African countries on poor African lands.
Table 7 and 8 present the projections of the United Nations Environment Program (UNEP)
regarding the carbon emission for the African countries. These tables, in a way, summarize the
most serious danger due to deforestation and pollution in Africa. If one adds up all the various
environmental threats outlined above the entire continent would seem to be advancing steadily
towards ecological disaster.
pg_0019
19
Table 7: Low Base Case Carbon Emission Projections for Deforestation of
All Tropical Forests for 1980-2050 (in billion tunes of carbon per year)
Countries
1980
2000
2025
2060
AFRICA
Algeria
Angola
3.9
4.4
5.0
5.8
Burundi
Cameroon
11.0
12.6
14.1
15.8
Cen. Afr. Rep. 2.5
2.9
3.3
3.8
Chad
3.0
3.4
3.8
4.2
Congo
2.4
2.7
3.1
3.4
Equ. Guinea
0.2
0.2
0.3
0.3
Benin
1.7
1.9
2.2
2.4
Mali
1.6
1.7
1.9
2.1
Tanzania
3.5
3.9
4.4
4.9
Burkina Faso 3.0
3.4
3.8
4.2
Mozambique 5.0
5.8
6.3
7.1
Niger
1.1
1.3
1.6
1.6
Nigeria
23.4
28.6
29.9
33.3
Guinea
1.8
2.1
2.4
2.6
Rwanda
0.2
0.2
0.3
0.3
Uganda
1.6
1.8
2.0
2.2
Zambia
3.0
3.4
3.8
4.2
Botswana
0.5
0.6
0.6
0.7
Liberia
2.9
3.3
3.7
4.1
Namibia
0.7
0.8
0.8
1.0
Ethiopia
5.6
6.3
7.1
7.9
Gambia
0.1
0.2
0.2
0.2
Ghana
3.8
4.3
4.8
5.4
Guinea
3.9
4.4
5.0
5.6
Kenya
1.2
1.4
1.5
1.7
Malawi
11.1
12.6
14.2
15.9
Sierra
0.4
0.4
0.5
0.5
Ivory Coast
41.4
46.9
53.0
59.1
Madagascar
8.7
9.9
11.1
12.4
Togo
0.4
0.4
0.5
0.6
Senegal
2.1
2.3
2.6
2.9
Somalia
0.8
0.9
1.0
1.1
Zimbabwe
3.0
3.4
3.8
4.2
Gabon
1.6
1.8
2.0
2.2
Sudan
18.8
21.3
24.1
26.9
Zaire
24.8
28.1
31.7
36.4
TROPICAL
AFRICA
200.3
227.0
256.4
285.8
pg_0020
20
Table 8: High Base Case: Net Flux from Population-based Rates of Forest Conversion
and High Forest Biomass Estimates
Countries
1980
2000
2025
2060
AFRICA
Algeria
Angola
8.4
9.6
13.8
15.5
Burundi
Cameroon
23.7
27.4
39.2
46.9
Cen. Afr. Rep. 5.6
6.3
9.0
10.8
Chad
6.4
7.4
10.6
12.6
Congo
5.2
6.0
8.5
10.2
Equ. Guinea
0.5
0.6
0.8
0.9
Benin
3.8
4.4
6.3
7.6
Mali
3.2
3.7
5.3
6.3
Tanzania
47.7
8.6
12.3
14.7
Burkina Faso 6.4
7.4
10.6
12.6
Mozambique 10.6
12.3
17.6
21.1
Niger
2.4
2.8
4.0
4.8
Nigeria
90.4
104.4
149.6
179.0
Guinea
4.6
5.3
7.6
9.0
Rwanda
0.6
0.6
0.8
0.9
Uganda
3.3
3.9
5.5
6.6
Zambia
6.4
7.4
10.6
12.6
Botswana
1.1
1.2
1.8
2.1
Liberia
11.8
13.7
19.6
23.6
Namibia
1.6
1.8
2.6
3.0
Ethiopia
11.8
13.7
19.6
23.6
Gambia
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
Ghana
11.7
13.6
19.4
23.2
Guinea
13.4
16.4
22.1
28.6
Kenya
2.6
3.0
4.3
5.1
Malawi
23.8
27.6
39.6
47.2
Sierra
1.6
1.8
2.6
3.0
Ivory Coast
162.7
176.3
252.6
302.3
Madagascar
36.2
40.7
58.3
69.8
Togo
1.1
1.2
1.8
2.1
Senegal
4.4
5.1
7.3
8.7
Somalia
1.5
1.8
2.6
3.0
Zimbabwe
6.4
7.4
10.6
12.6
Gabon
3.3
3.9
5.6
6.6
Sudan
40.4
46.7
66.9
80.0
Zaire
53.2
61.4
88.0
105.3
TROPICAL
AFRICA
558.3
653.9
937.1
1121.3
pg_0021
21
III
The Way Forward: Sustainable Development with Equity in Africa
African Capabilities
Faced with the disheartening trends outlined in the last section, one reaction in the policy
circles internationally has been to write Africa off as a lost cause. A somewhat different response
by the multilateral development agencies has been to advocate structural adjustment according to
“the Washington Consensus.” Here I would like to advance a third way of dealing with the
African crisis. This alternative is based on an ecologically sound and equitable growth-oriented
program for the African economies in the future.
The philosophical starting point in this approach to African development is the idea of
human development as an increase in the capabilities of people. The question one has to pose at this
point is simply this: What kind of adjustment is an equitable adjustment. Traditionally, economists have been
reluctant to answer this question except in very weak normative terms. The ordinal approach only considers Pareto
improving allocations where at least one individual is better off and no one else is worse off than before as a
superior outcome. The stronger normative approach is to take a utilitarian cardinal social welfare function and use
some proxy for distributive justice as an argument in this function. For example, the distribution of income can be
such a proxy variable. Many of the indexes of income inequality (e.g. Gini index, Atkinson index, Theil index,
etc.) and poverty can be derived from such considerations. The Human Development Index (HDI) is computed
according to a methodology which uses an income adjusting method in the spirit of Atkinson. The attraction of
this method is considerable and I see nothing wrong with using it imaginatively as the HDI approach tries to do.
16
pg_0022
22
At the same time, the theoretical criticisms by Sen
17
; Nussbaum
18
and others that this approach reduces all
qualities into quanta of utilities is a serious one. Nussbaum
19
gives a graphic example of this by quoting the
exchange between Mr. Gradgrind, economist and grief-stricken father, and his pupil Bitzer. Bitzer outdoes his
mentor by adhering to a strict code of utilitarian rationality that cannot comprehend a father's grief. I have pursued
a similar line of criticism in a number of recent papers.
20
In discussing equity, therefore, I wish to take a version of the social capabilities approach. Structural
Adjustments in order to be defensible, must be proven to be capability enhancing, or at least not to be
capability-reducing. The first type of SAPs I will characterize as "strongly equitable" SAPs (SESAPs). The
second type will be called weakly equitable SAPS (WESAPs). But first we need to ask: what is meant by
capabilities.
Capabilities can be construed as general powers of human body and mind that can be acquired,
maintained, nurtured and developed. They can also (under circumstances such as malnutrition or severe
confinement) be diminished and even completely lost. I have emphasized elsewhere the irreducibly social (not
merely biological) character of these human capabilities.
21
Sen himself emphasizes "a certain sort of possibility or
opportunity for functioning."
22
Assessment of SAPs from a Capability Perspective
In order to assess SAPs from a capabilities perspective we need to go further and try to describe more
concretely what some of the basic capabilities may be. David Crocker has given an admirable summary of both
Nussbaum's and Sen's approach to capabilities in a recent essay. Mainly relying on Nussbaum,
23
but also on other
pg_0023
23
sources (shown below), he has compiled a list that is worth reproducing here:
Basic Human Functional Capabilities (N and S stand for "Nussbaum" and "Sen", respectively; the quoted
items come from Nussbaum
24
unless otherwise noted).
1. Capabilities in Relation to Mortality
1.1. N and S: "Being able to live to the end of a complete human life, so far as is possible"
25
1.2. N: Being able to be courageous
26
2. Bodily Capabilities
2.1. N and S: "Being able to have good health."
27
2.2. N and S: "Being able to be adequately nourished."
28
2.3. N and S: "Being able to have adequate shelter"
29
2.4. N: "Being able to have opportunities for sexual satisfaction"
2.5. N and S: "Being able to move about from place to place"
30
3. Pleasure
3.1. N and S: "Being able to avoid unnecessary and non-useful pain and to have pleasurable
experiences
31
4. Cognitive Virtues
4.1. N: "Being able to use the five senses"
4.2. N: "Being able to imagine"
4.3. N: "Being able to think and reason"
4.4. N and S: "Being acceptably well-informed"
32
5. Affiliation I (Compassion)
5.1. N: "Being able to have attachments to things and persons outside ourselves"
5.2. N: "Being able to love, grieve, to feel longing and gratitude"
6. Virtue of Practical Reason (Agency)
6.1. N: "Being able to form a conception of the good"
33
S: "Capability to choose"
34
; "ability to form goals, commitments, values"
35
6.2. N and S: "Being able to engage in critical reflection about the planning of one's own life"
36
7. Affiliation II (Friendship and Justice)
7.1. N: "Being able to live for and to others, to recognize and show concern for other human beings,
to engage in various forms of familial and social interaction"
7.1.1. N: Being capable of friendship
37
S: Being able to visit and entertain friends
38
pg_0024
24
7.1.2. S: Being able to participate in the community
39
7.1.3. N: Being able to participate politically
40
and being capable of justice
41
8. Ecological Virtue
8.1. N: "Being able to live with concern for and in relation to animals, plants and the world of nature"
9. Leisure
9.1. N: "Being able to laugh, to play, to enjoy recreational activities"
10. Separateness
10.1. N: "Being able to live one's own life and nobody else's
10.2. N: "Being able to live in one's very own surroundings and context"
11. Self-respect
11.1. S: "Capability to have self-respect"
42
11.2. S: "Capability of appearing in public without shame"
43
12. Human Flourishing
12.1. N: "Capability to live a rich and fully human life, up to the limit permitted by natural
possibilities"
44
12.2. S: "Ability to achieve valuable functionings"
45
To facilitate this ordering, it might be better for practical rationality and affiliation to "infuse" but not
"organize" the other virtues. Crocker contrasts Nussbaum's approach with Sen's. Sen's and Nussbaum's
lists differ at a few points. For Sen, the bodily capabilities and functionings (2) are intrinsically good and
not, as they are in some dualistic theories of the good life, merely instrumental means to other (higher)
goods. In interpreting Aristotle, Nussbaum distinguishes between bodily functionings that are chosen
and intentional, for instance, "chosen self-nutritive and reproductive activities that form part of a
reason-guided life" and those that are non-intentional, such as digestion and other "functioning of the
bodily system in sleep." She may want to say that intentional bodily actions that lead to being
well-nourished and healthy are intrinsically good, but that being healthy or having good digestion are not
functionings (because not intentional) and are valuable only because of what they enable us to do.
Another option open to her would be to adopt Sen's view that bodily states and processes, whether
intentional or not, both as intrinsically and instrumentally good but as less valuable than other inherently
good capabilities/functionings.
Furthermore, Nussbaum has included items 5 and 8-10, for which Sen has no counterparts. These
items are welcome features. Item 8, which I have called "ecological virtue", is an especially important
recent addition to Nussbaum's outlook. In a period when many are exploring ways of effecting a
convergence between environmental ethics and development ethics, it is important that an essentially
anthropocentric ethic "make room" for respect for other species and for ecological systems. Worth
considering is whether Nussbaum's "ecological virtue" is strong enough. Perhaps it should be
formulated to read: "Being able to live with concern for and in relation to animals, plants, and nature as
intrinsically valuable." Item 9 injects some appealing playfulness in a list otherwise marked by the
pg_0025
25
"spirit of seriousness." What explains the presence of these items on Nussbaum's list, their absence on
Sen's list, and, more generally, the more concrete texture often displayed in Nussbaum's descriptions.
One hypothesis is that the differences are due to Nussbaum's greater attention, in her Level 1, to the
limits, vulnerabilities, and needs of human existence. Further, it may be that Nussbaum's richer
conception of human beings derives from making use of the story-telling imagination far more than the
scientific intellect."
46
On the other hand, Sen helpfully includes the good of self-respect, a virtue that
enables him to find common ground with Rawls and to establish links with the Kantian ethical tradition,
in which moral agents have the obligation to respect all persons, including themselves, as
ends-in-themselves.
47
Both Sen and Nussbaum agree, however, that these capabilities are distinct and of central importance.
One cannot easily trade off one dimension of capability against another. At most, one can do so in a very limited
way. They cannot be reduced to a common measure such as utility.
As Crocker points out, "capability ethic" has implications for freedom, rights and justice going far beyond
simple distribution of income considerations. If one accepts the capability approach as a serious foundation for
human development,
48
then it follows that going beyond distributive justice is necessary for a complete evaluation
of the impact of economic policies.
In evaluating SAPs from this perspective not only do we wish to pose the question of efficiency but also
the whole set of questions regarding human freedom. In particular, the positive human freedom to be or to do
certain things. Thus, creation of markets and efficient production by itself would mean very little if it led to a
lopsided distribution of benefits. Worse yet, if SAPs led to phenomena such as reduced life expectancy, increased
unemployment, reduced consumption levels for many and deprivation for certain groups such as women and
minorities then they will not even be WESAPs. On the contrary, they will be strongly inequitable from the
capability perspective.
pg_0026
26
This abstract discussion actually has direct relevance for the African situation. Unless an alternative is
found, the future capability enhancement of Africans cannot be assured. This assessment follows in a transparent
way from the evidence presented in the previous section.
An Alternative Structural Adjustment Program (ASAP) for Capability-enhancement in Africa
Let us go back to the beginning and reconsider the Washington consensus outlined in section I. In light of
what I have said so far it must be apparent that I do not consider this approach to be so much wrong as incomplete
and to some extent inconsistent with the goals of human development. I have given critical and technical analysis
of these programs elsewhere.
49
At the risk of distortion by leaving out some details and nuances I will attempt a
quick summary here.
Basically, the conventional SAPs focus on short to medium run results regarding inflation and
balance-of-payments equilibrium.
50
In the case of many African economies, as discussed in section I, privatization
itself may have become a goal for structural reform. Likewise, market-making can also become a goal in itself.
Not enough recognition has been accorded to the economic side effects such as unemployment or (at least a
temporary) lowering of output. Social dimensions of adjustment came to be recognized even later. The status of
vulnerable groups such as women, children, or the poor do not often figure explicitly in these programs. In order to
design a capability-enhancing alternative SAP (ASAP) for Africa the following elements must figure prominently:
(1) A clear recognition of the status of the different socio-economic groups in African countries in terms of
their economic and overall level of well-being.
.
(2) A list of priorities in terms of economic and social goals must be prepared. In the case of incompatibilities
of some of these goals, the question of trade-offs must be raised and resolved explicitly rather than
implicitly through the logic of the market.
pg_0027
27
(3) In particular, issues of fair inter-regional allocation of resources or opportunities must be addressed
explicitly.
(4) Human development indicators based on the capability framework must become an integral part of
ASAP.
(5) As table 9 shows, the record of Africa in the wake of SAPs with regards to gender disparities is not
flattering. Therefore, gender-justice must become a central part of ASAP for Africa -- not a peripheral
issue to be ignored or to be resolved later after enough growth has taken place.
(6) As alluded to in the discussion of African environment, sustainable development, with ecological effects
of adjustment included, must become the conceptual center of thinking about SAPs in these economies.
(7) It follows then that ecological and distributional issues need to be explicitly addressed in any such
program. This implies that there will be a need for careful inter-disciplinary studies on probable impacts
of a policy package before its implementation. It also implies the need for follow-up studies in order to
assess the after-effects of a SAP.
51
It should be clear by now that no African economy has been provided with an opportunity to design a
SAP with the above provisos in mind. However, that does not mean that it is impossible or unrealistic to try to do
so. For example, the struggle of Ghana to manage its economy while keeping the goals of creating social
capabilities may offer some lessons -- positive and negative -- in this respect.
pg_0028
28
Table 9: Critical Gender Disparities in Developing Countries
gap in literacy
rate, 1992
material
mortality rate
(per 100,000
births) 1988
gap in labor force
participation
1990-92
administrators
and managers (%
female), 1980-89
parliament (% of
seats by women),
1992
Swaziland
400
52
Lesotho
350
79
Zimbabwe
330
15
12
Congo
63
900
64
Cameroon 64
550
43
6
12
Kenya
400
67
3
Namibia
400
32
7
Madagascar 83
600
67
Ghana
73
700
67
9
8
Zambia
80
600
67
33
3
Nigeria
65
750
49
2
Zaire
73
700
56
5
Senegal
48
750
35
12
Liberia
58
600
45
6
Tanzania
600
92
11
Equa. Guinea
800
56
Sudan
28
700
41
5
Burundi
66
800
113
10
Rwanda
58
700
117
17
Uganda
56
700
69
13
Benin
50
800
32
6
Malawi
500
104
12
Mozambique 47
800
92
16
Cen. Aft. Rep. 48
650
89
4
Ethiopia
900
69
Djibouti
740
0
Guinea-Bissau 48
1000
72
13
Somalia
39
900
64
Gambia
41
1000
69
15
8
Mali
59
850
19
2
Chad
43
800
20
Niger
85
850
89
6
Leone
35
1000
43
Burkina Faso 32
750
96
3
Guinea
37
1000
43
Judged by the evidence presented in the previous section, it would appear that SAPs in
pg_0029
29
Africa over the past decade led not to even a weak equity for the great majority of the population.
The conditions of the vulnerable groups, in particular of women and children, have worsened in
many areas. Inequality and poverty have also increased. On the strength of the empirical evidence,
the current international economic policy towards Africa must be declared strongly inequitable.
If the current conditions in Africa send a strong message that existing adjustment efforts
are not appropriate. What then are appropriate policies consistent with the new approach outlined
above.
In the light of the above criteria for ASAP alternative policies for Africa must address
initially debt rescheduling, canceling and refinancing. Specifically, the creation of a multilateral
debt facility for the highly indebted poor and some highly indebted middle income countries
would be a step in the right direction. The World Bank, the IMF and the group of creditor
countries known as the Paris Club, recently approved a plan to relieve the massive debt load of
some of the world’s heavily indebted poor countries (HIPCs). The countries to be assisted under
this program are those that have undertaken economic reforms but still have extremely high levels
of external debt relative to their export earnings.
Officials of the World Bank and the IMF have said that eight countries would probably
benefit in the first round of debt relief, and perhaps twelve others might qualify in the future. The
first beneficiary is likely to be an African country--probably Uganda. In Table 10 of the eight
HIPCs listed six are African countries.
pg_0030
30
Table 10: External Debt of Selected HIPCs in 1994
Country Annual Per Capita
GNP (in US dollars)
Debt as Percentage of
GNP
Debt as Percentage of
Exports
Debt Service as
Percentage of
Exports
Bolivia
770
89.4
390.1
28.2
Ethiopia
100
109.8
630.0
11.5
Mali
250
151.8
589.2
27.5
Mozambique
90
450.4
1,388.7
23.0
Nicaragua
340
800.6
2,286.1
38.0
Tanzania
140
229.5
877.5
20.5
Uganda
190
88.1
1,042.7
45.6
Zambia
350
204.3
560.1
31.5
All Low-&
Middle-Income
Countries
1,090
37.6
162.8
16.6
Source: World Bank, World Development Report 1996
While a step in the right direction, this scheme is far from adequate. HIPCs have
debt-to-export ratio of over 500 percent as a group. For some African countries such as
Mozambique, it is over 1000 percent. However, there are more than half a dozen other African
countries with debt-to-export ratios of over 200 percent. From an economic point of view, a ratio
of over 100 percent means that export earnings by themselves can not cover the debt during the
relevant economic period—usually the fiscal year. Given the argument developed here, debt relief
needs to be extended to most if not all of these African countries. The proposed relief for HIPCs
is estimated to cost between $5.6 billion and $7.7 billion. The Paris Club countries can offer up to
80 percent reduction of eligible bilateral debt; the World Bank, African Development Bank and
other multilateral development banks and individual countries (most notably U.S., UK, and
France) could contribute to the trust fund to purchase the additional outstanding debt. Finally, the
IMF could contribute to the proposed expanded initiative by allocating more funds to its existing
subsidized loan facilities. However, in the case of IMF not realizing the stringent conditionalities
pg_0031
31
will mean that most African countries, as in the recent past, will be unable to use its SAF or ESAF
facilities. Additionally, the IMF could also allocate special new SDR’s to the severely indebted
African countries.
In this context, a new contract more generous than the Naples Terms for bilateral debt
relief is clearly called for. Partly because of the stringent conditions of Naples Terms, for instance,
Uganda’s debt service was reduced by only 2 percent. Countries like Zambia now spend thirty
times more in debt repayments than on education. In the spirit of Naples Terms, a new bilateral
debt relief scheme needs to be set up without conditionalities to provide up to 75 percent reduction
in the stock of bilateral debt of African countries.
From the perspective of the African countries, a debtors cartel might have been a strong
response earlier. But the time for such radical responses may have passed. Therefore, incremental
proposals like the ones above need to be pursued vigorously.
Social Expenditure Conditionality for Africa
The best conditionality that the bilateral and multilateral lenders can impose on the African
counties is a social expenditure conditionality. This could be a specific African version of the
global 20:20 proposal as presented in the Human Development Report 1994 and further refined in
the interagency consultations within the UN system. According to the 20:20 proposal, the
developing countries should earmark at least 20% of their national budgets and donor nations 20%
of their aid budgets for human development expenditures. These are defined to include primary
health care, basic education, rural and peri-urban water supply, essential family planning service
and nutrition programs for the most deprived groups in society.
pg_0032
32
If implemented in African countries between $5 and $10 billion may become available
annually for such human development priority expenditures. It can be expected that in two
decades (the goal for the world as a whole is to do this in one decade) the now heavily indebted
African countries could ensure that:
1. Everyone will gain access to basic education.
2. Everyone will gain access to primary health care facilities and to safe drinking water.
3. All children will be immunized, and most childhood diseases eliminated.
4. Maternal mortality rates will be halved
5. All willing couples will have access to family planning services, and the groundwork will be
laid for stabilizing the world’s population by 2015.
6. severe malnutrition will be eliminated, and moderate malnutrition reduced by half.
7. The worst forms of human deprivation will be eliminated through the provision of certain basic
social services. Although the proposal does not deal with many aspects of global
poverty—particularly with employment and income generation—it does contain certain
attractive features. For example, it would;
-Help slow population growth by focusing on universal female education, primary health care and
other elements of an essential human development program needed to create the underlying
conditions for declining fertility.
-Improve the prospects for global human security downstream by eliminating upstream the global
spread of many dangerous diseases. For example, AIDS cost $240 billion during the 1980s;
preventive health care would have cost only a fraction of that.
-Improve the global environment by addressing some of the worst aspects of the pollution and
poverty—polluted water, unknown diseases, galloping population growth.
-Enhance human capital and its competitiveness. Consequently poor people will be better able to
use market opportunities. This will ultimately lead to a greater demand for goods through the
multiplier effect. Growth will be affected favorably as well.
In view of the serious nature of the economic and social crisis in Africa, the compact may
have to be more than 20:20 if faster progress is to be made. A 30:30 compact will destroy the neat
ocular analogy with perfect vision, but will enable the African nations to achieve the human
development goals outlined above in half the time. Because of large initial fixed costs of the
programs and the presence of economies of scale and complementarities an extra dollar after a
certain initial amount is actually more productive than before. Therefore, increasing outlays by
pg_0033
33
only 50% beyond the 20:20 compact will have almost twice the effect. This is encouraging and
should prompt some serious thinking about increasing human development related expenditures
among African and international policy circles.
Finally, an Environmental Defense Fund for Africa (EDFA) needs to be set up. This could
be facilitated both by the multilateral aid agencies and the developed country donors. Local
campaigns to stop environmental deterioration can be supported through this facility as can be the
NGOs with programs for sustainable development, given the circumstances described earlier in
Chapter II.
Ultimately, the African nations themselves have the primary responsibility in meeting the
challenges described. But without coordinated efforts and aid from the advanced industrial
nations, no policy for sustainable human development can succeed in Africa.
IV
Rethinking U.S. Economic Policy Toward Africa
A New Vision.
In spite of the prevailing gloom regardin
g Africa among some circles in
Washington there are some hopeful signs. In 1994, John F. Hicks, the Assistant
Administrator of the Bureau for Africa of AID outlined in general the Clinton
administration ’s policy priorities for Africa in following terms:
52
1. to help Africans build stable, honest and democratic governments, including
stimulating popular participation and full respect for basic human rights;
pg_0034
34
“small ” initial disturbances resulting in large and
prolonged systemic instability.
53 In an uncertain world, it is better to insure
against the possibility of such as global catastrophe by sending timely and
pg_0035
35
—but it is safe to assume
that they will not be pleasant for the developed economies either.
Perhaps, the greatest threat to the world from a possible catastrophe in
Africa is to e cology of the planet as a whole. Although precise estimates are
hard to come by, ultimately deforestation and other environmental disasters in
Africa will definitely constitute to global warming, global atmospheric conditions,
and other global ecological
problems.
Helping Africa is, therefore, not merely a humanitarian concern. It is
dictated
by
a
deep
realism
in
international
economic
relations
based
on
enlightened,
long - term national interests of developed nations such as the U.S..
Need for Specificit y
pg_0036
36
pg_0037
37
’s needs
to be made an integral part of the U.S. aid policy for Africa. The recent
proposal advanced by NGO groups such as the Development Gap and Friends of
the Earth - U.S., among others, calls for an independent
agency to be created.
Furthermore, according to this proposal, this
“Agency for International
Cooperation ” will have room for a Development Assistance Board. The structure
and governance of this board should be such that NGOs based among the people
can get funding for development without political or bureaucratic interference
from above. Special emphasis must be given the role of these indigenous NGO
’s.
Cooperation among domestic and foreign NGO ’s for specific and appropriate
projects in Africa could c
onsiderably brighten the prospects for genuine
development there. A related policy issue here is the possibility of bypassing
the existing rigid hierarchy of both aid operatives and domestic bureaucracy.
To the extent indigenous traditional sectors will
maintain viable
organizational capacities NGO ’s can encourage and foster local self
- reliant
development
by
working
with
the
people
(particularly
in
the
rural
area)
directly.
pg_0038
38
pg_0039
39
pg_0040
40
“Rather than retreat from Africa, the United States should form an international partnership
with African states in their determined struggle against underdevelopment and to enhance
the dignity of all peoples on this troubled continent. African advancement assures our own.
By helping them to strengthen their human rights conditions we reaffirm our commitment
to these values at home.”55
The eight concrete policy initiatives outlines above are some of the most
important and immediately feasible steps that the U.S. can take. The list is
not meant to be exhaustive. It is my hope that by focusing on the most urgent
tasks, it will be possible to persuade the U.S. policymakers to move quickly in
the desired directi on. At the same time, this monograph can serve as a basis
for
further
discussion
and
refinements
of
specific
policies.
The
economic
problems
of Africa are not just African problems. They are global in their origin and
scope. They also will require glob
al cooperation for their solution. This is
the basic message of this monograph.
pg_0041
41
Appendix. IMF and World Bank Adjustment Approaches: Stylized Descriptions
Since both the IMF and the World Bank have been so influential in designing many aspects of the
structural adjustments in both LDCs and transitional economies, it is useful to present in a stylized way the formal
structures of their approaches. Needless to say the equations described below cannot capture all or even most of
the details of SAPs. What they can do is to bring out the formal logic of the conventional thinking which is often
implicit in the arguments and the policy advice given by these international bodies. The hope here is to generate a
rigorous discussion about the issues by clarifying the basic logical structure of the standard SAPs.
The Theoretical Basis of Adjustment Programs
Why the IMF does what it does
The theoretic basis of IMF adjustment programs rests on financial programming, the analytical
foundations of which are drawn from Polak
56
and Robichek.
57
The modeling process is referred to as financial
programming, an integration of monetary and credit elements in BOP analysis, which derives a linkage between
the domestic part of the money stock (credit) and international reserve changes. This approach begins from the
simple accounting identity showing change in the money stock as the result of changes in its domestic and
international components.
In the approach the BOP is shown as the difference between the change in money supply and that in
domestic credit. The absorption approach is adopted to include income and expenditure relationships as well as the
impact of capital movements in an open economy. In this approach the current account (CA) deficit is equal to the
difference between income (Y) and absorption (A). The current account is matched by changes in the net foreign
assets of domestic banks (
.
R) and in the net foreign indebtedness of nonbank residents (
.
FI). Hence:
CA =
.
R -
.
FI (1)
Combining the current account identity with equation (1) yields
CA +
.
FI =
.
M -
.
D (2)
where
.
M is the change in the money supply and
.
D is the change in net domestic assets of banks (credit).
This equation can be written in terms of the difference between nominal income and absorption, as
Y - A +
.
FI =
.
M -
.
D (3)
Assuming that the change in nominal money balances are independent of
.
D, the conclusion is that a ceiling for
.
D will determine the balance of payments (
.
R).
To specify where the improvements in the balance of payments will take place, the BOP is decomposed
pg_0042
42
into its different parts and the demand for imports added as a second behavioral relationship. The simplified
framework shows imports as a constant function of only real income.
The BOP identity is
.
R = X - IM +
.
FI (4)
where X and IM are exports and imports, respectively, in domestic currency. Based on projections of the values
for exports and capital flows, the targeted value of imports is derived as a residual of the preceding equation
IM
*
=
.
R
*
- ( X +
.
F I) (5)
where IM
*
is the targeted value of imports,
.
R
*
the targeted BOP in the program period, X and
.
FI are the
projected values of exports and capital flows, respectively.
To include elements of fiscal policy, three ex-post identities are specified. Initially, the change in net
foreign indebtedness of a country is taken as the sum of changes in the public sector (
.
FI
g
) and private sector
(
.
FI
p
) net foreign debt position:
.
FI =
.
FI
p
+
.
FI
g
(6)
Next the public and private sector credit changes are decomposed as
.
D =
.
D
g
+
.
D
p
(7)
where
.
D
g
and
.
D
p
are changes in credit to the public and private sectors, respectively.
Third, the government budget constraint is shown through deficit financing by either net borrowing from
abroad or net borrowing from domestic banks:
G - T =
.
D
g
+
.
FI
g
(8)
where G is total government expenditure and T is total revenue, with the difference representing the government
deficit.
The three equations provide the rationale for restricting government spending, specifically through
ceilings on domestic and foreign borrowing. This policy is directed toward two consequences of government
spending: fiscal deficits and crowding out.
In the financial programming framework, the exchange rate plays a role through the effects on money
demand. Depreciation of a fixed exchange rate results in a decline in real absorption by creating excess demand
for real cash balances. At the same time, by affecting the incentives to domestic supplier of exports and import
substitutes and spending on exportables and imports, it affects the composition of domestic expenditure on
pg_0043
43
domestic and foreign goods.
The World Bank’s Model
Unlike the Fund's concern with temporary BOP imbalances, the World Bank focuses on the real
economy and growth in the medium term. Through the Revised Minimum Standard Model (RMSM), it
emphasizes savings, capital inflows, and investment. According to Khan,
58
the RMSM posits four additional
relationships to those in the IMF model.
Assuming that an incremental capital-output ratio (ICOR) is given historically or technologically, output is
specified as a function of the level of investment:
.
y
*
=
r
-1
.
k (9)
where
.
y
*
is the output target,
r
is ICOR, and
.
k is total domestic investment.
In the model, exports are exogenously determined, although this is later relaxed, and there is a stable
relationship between GDP and imports. The savings rate is also stable and historically given, yielding a
consumption function such as
C
p
= (1 - s) (y
*
- $
T ) (10)
where C
p
is private sector consumption, s is the ratio of private savings to disposable income, and $
T is taxes.
For output determination the national income identity is written as
.
K = s(y - $
T - C
p
) + ( $
T - $
C
G
) + (Z - X) (11)
where C
G
is public sector consumption, Z is foreign sector revenues in the form of imports by the domestic
economy, and X is foreign sector spending on domestic exports. More importantly, the national income identity
may be formulated as
.
K = s(y
*
- $
T ) + ( $
T - $
C
G
) + (ay
*
- X ) (12)
which establishes a positive relationship between income and investment through the aggregate demand curve. A
rise in output increases both domestic savings according to given rate, s, and the inflow of foreign saving according
to the marginal propensity to import, a. Investment increases in respect to saving on a one-for-one basis.
The positive relationship between investment and output can also be obtained by rewriting equation (9) as
.
K = y
*
- y
-1
, (13)
pg_0044
44
where y
-1
is last period's real GDP. In this model, output and BOP targets can be reconciled either through control
over net capital inflows or though perfect elasticity of foreign capital. In this way change in net foreign assets
(
.
F), as a policy variable, can be chose as
.
$
F = X - ay
*
-
.
R
*
, (14)
where
.
R
*
is a BOP target. The values of
.
y
*
and
.
R
*
can be attained through C
G
, $
T , and
.
$
F , given an
exogenously derived export projection.
The World Bank model provides for exchange rate adjustment too. Including the effects of the exchange
rate on imports and exports, equation (14) can now be written as
.
$
F = -ay
*
+ (b + c) ê -
.
R
*
, (15)
where b is a parameter that measures the responsiveness of the volume of imports to the relative price of
importables, c is the coefficient of responsiveness of exports to relative prices, and e (with the assumption of
constant prices) is the real exchange rate. With three independent exogenous variables and eqations to solve three
endogenous variables, the model is fully determined now, even with a foreign exchange constraint.
Critical Voices Against Adjustment Models
The criticisms against the IMF and World Bank approaches are numerous and come from several
directions, from different strands of economists and political scientists. Therefore, we can attempt only a summary
here by concentrating on the economic and political economy components of the debate. However, even these are
impossible to present in their entirety. The structuralist challenge is particularly interesting. Structuralists draw
attention to institutional and technological factors that affect changes in the economy at any particular time. The
neo-structuralists argue that developing countries may respond to standard economic policies unexpectedly.
Therefore, a devaluation may cause output contraction, tight money may cause price rises due to higher interest
costs, inflation may become "inertial," and public investment may crowd in, instead of out, private investment. In
the long run, they observe that income distribution may condition growth and market liberalization, and unfettered
foreign capital flows may not be beneficial.
In Taylor's
59
theoretical analysis, the trade-liberalizing aspects of the IMF and World Bank models are
questioned. It is shown that export subsidies unambiguously increase capacity utilization, and with appropriate
multiplier values and intermediate import content of output, the trade balance improves as well, without unpleasant
side effects on interest rates and inflation. In the short run, liberalization can be self-defeating by liquidating wealth
and inducing recession. The long-run consequences can be counterproductive too. His general conclusion is that
"at least in the short to medium run, directed policy makes sense. Maneuvers such as quotas and subsidies (or
multiple exchange rates) and price controls, instead of changes in the exchange rate, monetary and fiscal policy,
avoid unfavourable economy-wide side-effects."
On the Left the attack is launched by Onimode.
60
His criticism evolves around the theme that the IMF
and World Bank address what he refers to as "at best subsidiary or auxiliary structures" (prices, trade, money, and
pg_0045
45
foreign exchange). The relevant "fundamental structures" that demand adjustment are those of the capitalist
international division of labour, of production, consumption, accumulation, technology, and dependency in the
poor countries. Hence IMF and World Bank programs operate to aggravate, rather than ameliorate, the
crisis-generating structures in Africa and other poor countries. In sum, he argues that BOP disequilibria are
inevitable in low-income countries because of the combined effects of devaluation, liberalized imports, and the
withdrawal of exchange controls.
Several aspects of programs have become controversial even by centrist standards. The most often
discussed aspect relates to the social impact of adjustment on the poor and vulnerable. This concern has pushed its
way to the forefront of the debate, since the publication by the United Nations Children's Fund of the (UNICEF)
twin volumes, Adjustment with a Human Face.
61
The volumes draw attention to the disproportionate share of the
poor and vulnerable, particularly women and children, in the adjustment burden. Since then a strong "pro-poor"
theme has developed in the literature. Publications such as Susan George's A Fate Worse than Debt have
strengthened this theme. According to the United Nations Economic Commission for Africa (ECA) the standard
models "not only ignore the human dimension, but also tend to worsen the well-being of large categories of the
population, especially the poor and vulnerable." The major cause of this is public sector budget retrenchment,
which has also strained governments' institutional capacity to the limit.
Similarly, the models have been criticized for ignoring the impact of reduced real wages on productivity
and living standards. In fact, in many low-income countries the centrality given to the BOP is itself wrong, since
the most important problem is that of falling or inadequate real incomes. Therefore, if poverty is perceived as the
main problem, cutting wages of ordinary, low-paid employees to achieve profitability and economic growth is
unacceptable.
Critics have also pointed out a problem of economic logic and deflationary bias. The logical issue has its
origins in John Stuart Mill's concept of reciprocal demand, elaborated in his Principles of Political Economy. The
idea is that the exports of one country are the imports of another; hence the deficits and debts of one are the
surpluses and credits of another country. Failure to recognize this is what creates the deflationary bias of the
standard adjustment modes. This has also clear Keynesian implications of global deflation under conditions of
reciprocal lowering of demand.
Finally, a note on devaluation, which apart from distributional issues has received the heaviest barrage of
criticism: There is a long tradition in the literature on the contractionary effects of devaluation and its failure to
improve the BOP. The rationale for devaluation is that there are excessive imports and inadequate exports. The
two shortcomings of this approach are that it may ignore the share of debt-service payments in the BOP deficit and
does not distinguish between essential imports and luxury imports. Inflation may be caused directly by higher
import costs and/or a nominal rise in food prices, unleashing demands for higher wages in the industrial sector,
which, if granted, would lead to higher industrial prices and the need for another devaluation. Even if the
inflationary pressures can be controlled, the implicit assumption that the demand and supply of tradables is elastic
has been widely questioned.
All this is not to deny the need for adjustment in the countries that need it. The real question has to do with
the type and purpose of the necessary adjustment. The criteria for ASAP discussed in the main body of the
monograph tried to address precisely these questions.
pg_0046
46
1
See for example, UNDP, Human Development Report, New York: Oxford University Press, 1996. For a discussion
of the African situation from the perspective of global justice, see Karamo Sonko and George W. Shepherd, Jr. (eds.),
Economic Justice in Africa: Adjustment and Sustainable Development, Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1994.
2
Of course, it is not being claimed that structural adjustments are not necessary. Later, in Chapter III, an alternative
structural adjustment program suitable for the particular economic and human conditions in Africa is presented. See
also, H.A. Khan, “Economic Modelling of Structural Adjustment Programs: Impact on Human Conditions,” Africa
Today, 37, No.4 (4
th
Quarter, 1990), 29-38.
3
See for example, A.K. Sen, Inequality Reexamined, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1992, 1992; Martha
Nussbaum and A.K. Sen (eds.), The Quality of Life, Osford: Clarendon Press, 1992.
4
See Martha Nussbaum and Jonathan Glover (eds.), Women, Culture and Development, Oxford: Clarendon Press,
1995. See also, H.A. Khan, “Resources, Capability and Regional Development,” in A. Kumssa and H.A. Khan (eds.),
Transitional Economies and Regional Economic Development Strategies, Nagoya: United Nations Centre for
Regional Development, 1996. And UNECA, African Alternative Framework to Structural Adjustment: Programmes
for Socio-Economic Recovery and Transfomation, Addis Ababa: Africa House, 1989.
5
John Williamson, ed., Latin American Adjustment: How Much Has Happened. (Washington, DC: IIE, 1990).
6
John Williamson ed., The Political Economy of Policy Reform (Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, 1994), p. 17.
7
ibid., p. 27. The debate on financial liberalization has been quite extensive. For an extensive survey see Maxwell
Fry, Money, Interest and Banking in Economic Development (Baltimore, MA; London: The Johns Hopkins
University Press, 1988), chapter 1-8. Karamo Sonko, Debt, Development and Equity in Africa (Lanham
University Press of America, 1994) and; Haider A. Khan, and Karamo Sonko, “A Multidimensional Approach to
Designing Effective Adjustment Programmes” in George Shepherd and Karamo Sonko, eds., Economic Justice in
Africa (Westport, CN: Greenwood Press, 1994); Khan and Sonko, “A Further Extension of Adjustment Models:
The Environment and Equity” in George Shepherd and Karamo Sonko, eds., Economic Justice in Africa
(Westport, CN: Greenwood Press, 1994) discuss the issues relevant to structural adjustment programs.
8
Williamson, ed., The Political Economy of Policy Reform, p. 27.
9
In Khan, “Economic Modeling of Structural Adjustment Programmes: Impact on Human Conditions,” Africa Today 37 (4: 1990): 29-38 , I
have explored the effects of a budgetary retrenchment on a developing economy. See also Erik Thorbecke et. al., Adjustment and Equity in
Indonesia (Paris: OECD, 1992), for an analysis of the impact of fiscal retrenchment.
10
Williamson, ed., The Political Economy of Policy Reform, p. 26.
11
From Africa: UN-NADAF NGO Statement, circulated online electoronically, apic@igc.apc.org., 21 September,
1996.
12
This apt term has been coined by Rene Lemarchand. See R. Lemarchand, “African Transitions to Democracy: An
Interim (and Mostly Pessimistic) Assessment,” Africa Insight, 22, NO.3 (1992), pp.178-85.
13
H.A. Khan and K. Sonko, “A Further Extension of Adjustment Models: The Environment and Equality,” in Sonko
and Shepherd, op.cit., pp.189-201.
14
Ibid., pp.197-99. See also A.S. Bhalla, Environment, Employment and Development, Geneva: International Labour
Office, 1992. Also, World Bank, Sub-Saharan Africa: From Crisis to Sustainable Growth, Washington DC, 1989.
15
Sylvain Bayalama, “Environmental Degradation, World Bank Projects, and the Right to a Clean Environment,” in
Sonko and Shepherd, op.cit., pp.63-78.
16
For a survey of the technical issues that arise in the construction of social and economic index numbers see S. Chakravarty, Ethical Social
Index Numbers (Berlin: Springer-Verlay, 1990). Various Human Development Reports including the most recent one (1995) discuss the use
of the Atkinson and other approaches to adjusting income. These reports also address other issues such as how to correct for gender bias.
17
Amartya Sen, Population Policy: Authoritarianism vs. Cooperation (London: London School of Economics, 1995); Sen, Inequality
Reexamined (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1992); Sen, “Welfare, Preference and Freedom” mimeographed, Harvard University
(1991); Sen, “On Indexing Primary Goods” mimeographed, Harvard University (1991); Sen, Commodities and Capabilities (Amsterdam:
North-Holland, 1985); and Sen, “The Moral Standing of Markets.” Social Philosophy and Policy 2 (1985): 1-19.
pg_0047
47
18
Martha Nussbaum, “Human Capabilities, Female Human Beings” in M. C. Nussbaum and J. Glover, eds., Women, Culture, and
Development (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1995); Nussbaum, “Aristotelian Social Democracy” in R. B. Douglass, G. R. Mara and H. S.
Richardson, eds., Liberalism and the Good (New York and London: Routledge, 1990), Nussbaum, Love's Knowledge: Essays on P hilosophy
and Literature (New York and Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1990), Nussbaum, “Nature, Function, and Capability: Aristotle on Political
Distribution,” Oxford Studies in Ancient Philosophy suppl. volume (1988): 145-84; Nussbaum, “Non-Relative Virtues: An Aristotelian
Approach,” Midwest Studies in Philosophy 13(1988): 32-53.
19
Nussbaum, “Human Capabilities, Female Human Beings,” p. 361.
20
Khan, “Economic Justice in the Age of Postmodernism” (Unpublished manuscript, GSIS, University of Denver, March 1995); Khan,
““Economic Justice and Democracy” (Unpublished manuscript, GSIS, University of Denver, March 1994); and Khan, “Markets, Structural
Adjustment and Democracy,” Relatciones Internationales 45 (1993).
21
That the capabilities are social does not mean that they are arbitrary. They are to be socially determined in a manner that will allow the
individual maximum amount of autonomy. In any existing social arrangement the capability of the individual may fall short, not because of
individual decisions but because the social arrangements do not allow the maximum to be achieved. This normative dimension of objective
thought about freedom in society is, in a sense, Hegelian. See for example Hegel’s Philosophy of Right, G.W.F. Hegel (Oxford: Clarendon
Press, 1942). See also, David Levine, Needs, Rights and the Market (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner, 1988); and Levine Wealth and Freedom:
An Introduction to Political Economy (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1995).
22
David Crocker, “Functioning and Capability: The Foundations of Sen's and Nussbaum's Development Ethic” in Martha Nussbaum and
Jonathon Glover, eds., Women, Culture and Development (New York: Oxford University Press, 1995), p. 162.
23
Nussbaum, “Aristotelian Social Democracy,” p. 225.
24
Ibid.
25
See Sen, “The Concept of Development” in H. Chenery and T. N. Srinivasan, eds., Handbook of Development
Economics vol I (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1988), p. 13.
26
See Nussbaum, Love's Knowledge: Essays on Philosophy and Literature, pp. 374, 378.
27
See Sen, “The Moral Standing of Markets,” p. 197.
28
Ibid.
29
See Sen, “Equality of What.” in S. M. McMurrin, ed., Tanner Lectures on Human Values i (Salt Lake City: University of Utah Press,
1980), p. 218.
30
See Sen, “Equality of What.,” p. 218; Sen, and Bernard Williams, Utilitarianism and Beyond (New York: Cambridge University Press,
1982), p. 20; Sen, “Rights and Agency,” Philosophy and Public Affairs 11 (1982): 200; Sen, “The Moral Standing of Markets,” p. 119; and
Sen, On Ethics and Economics (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1987), p. 64.
31
See Sen, “The Moral Standing of Markets,” p. 195-6; and Sen, On Ethics and Economics, p. 64.
32
Sen, “The Moral Standing of Markets,” p. 199; see Nussbaum, “Human Capabilities, Female Human Beings,”
p. 24.
33
See Sen and Williams, Utilitarianism and Beyond, p. 13.
34
Ibid.
35
Sen, “The Moral Standing of Markets,” p. 218; and Sen, “The Moral Standing of Markets,” p. 41.
36
See Sen, “The Moral Standing of Markets,” p. 218.
37
Nussbaum, “Human Capabilities, Female Human Beings,” p. 24.
38
Sen, “The Moral Standing of Markets,” p. 199.
39
Ibid.
40
Nussbaum, “Aristotelian Social Democracy,” p. 233.
41
Nussbaum, “Nature, Function, and Capability: Aristotle on Political Distribution,” p. 161.
42
Sen and Williams, Utilitarianism and Beyond, p. 20.
43
Sen, “The Moral Standing of Markets,” p. 199.
44
Nussbaum, “Aristotelian Social Democracy,” p. 217.
45
Sen, “The Moral Standing of Markets,” p. 200.
46
Nussbaum, “Aristotelian Social Democracy,” p. 217; see Nussbaum, The Fragility of Goodness: Luck and Ethics in Greek Tragedy and
pg_0048
48
Philosophy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986), p. 69; and Nassbaum, Love's Knowledge: Essays on Philosophy and Literature.
47
Crocker, “Functioning and Capability: The Foundations of Sen's and Nussbaum's Development Ethic,” pp. 176-77.
48
See Sen, Inequality Reexamined; “Economic Justice and Democracy” (Paper presented at the Conference on
Democracy, GSIS, Denver, April 1995); Khan, “Economic Justice in the Age of Postmodernism”
49
Khan, “Economic Modeling of Structural Adjustment Programs: Impact on Human Conditions,”; Khan,
“Democracy, Markets and the New Social Movements” (Paper presented at the Conference on Democracy, GSIS,
Denver, April 1993); Khan, “Markets, Structural Adjustment and Democracy,”; Khan and Sonko, “A
Multidimensional Approach to Designing Effective Adjustment Programs”; Khan and Sonko, “A Further
Extension of Adjustment Models: The Environment and Equity”; and Khan, Haider A. and Hitoshi Sogabe,
“Macroeconomic Effects of IMF Adjustment Policies” in George Shepherd and Karamo Sonko, eds., Economic
Justice in Africa (Westport, CN: Greenwood Press, 1994).
50
In Khan and Sogabe, “Macroeconomic Effects of IMF Adjustment Policies” we have attempted a statistical
evaluation of the impacts of the IMF programs for a large number of LDCs.
51
Thus one of the recommendations for future monographs in this series could be the carrying out of such studies and
publishing the reports as monographs in this series. Alternatively, a new series focusing particularly on the effects of
SAPs could be started. Some relevant existing studies are: “Africa: Multilateral Debt,” Washington DC: Bread for the
World, Feb. 5, 1996; Sigun I. Skoly, “Structural Adjustment and Development: Human Rights—An Agenda for
Change,” Human Rights Quarterly, No.4, 1993; The Brundland Report, World Commission on Environment and
Development: Our Common Future, Oxford: Oxford University Press. For debt reduction for Africa, “Multilateral
Debt Reduction: A Proposed Framework,” a position paper of the Canadian Inter-Church Coalition for Africa, January
1996 is an important recent contribution. On debt and aid, see, Christina Katsouris and Nil K. Bentsi-Enchill, “Africa
under Pressure from Falling Aid, Rising Debt,” African Recovery, United Nations, Vol.9, No.1, June 1995. Finally,
groups such as the Development Gap and American Committee on Africa are also producing reports that are timely
and relevant.
52
George W. Shepherd, Partnership with Africa: A New American Policy, Phelps-Stokes Fund
Africa Papers, July 1996, p.20.
53
See for instance, Brian Arthur, Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy, Ann Arbor: The
University of Michigan Press, 1994. Also, H.A. Khan, The Limits of National Innovation Systems: Technology,
Development and Democracy in the Postmodern World, Aldershot, U.K.: Edward Elgar, forthcoming.
54
George W. Shepherd, op.cit., p.1. In the area of U.S.-Africa trade in particular, Robert Browne has also emphasized
the idea of a partnership. See Robert Browne, The U.S. and Africa’s Trade: Prospects for Partnership, Amsterdam:
The Trans Africa Policy Institute, 1995
55 Ibid ., p.1.
56 J. Polak, "Monetary Analysis of Income Formation and Payments Problems," IMF Staff Papers (Washington, DC, November 1957).
57
W. Robichek, “Financial Programming Exercises of the International Monetary Fund in Latin America” (Address to a Seminar of Brazilian
Professors of Economics in Rio de Janeiro, September 1967).
58
H. A. Khan, “Economic Modeling of Structural Adjustment Programmes: Impact on Human Conditions,” Af rica Today 37 (4: 1990):
29-38.
59
L. Taylor, Stabilization and Growth in Developing Countries (U.K.: Harwood Academic Publishers, 1989).
60
B. Onimode, A Political Economy of the African Crisis (London: Zed Books, 1988).
61
UNICEF (G. A. Cornia, R. Jolly and F. Stewart, eds.), Adjustment with a Human Face: Protecting the Vulnerable and Promoting Growth
(Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1987).